Introduction:
The interface between anthropology and economics is as old
as the discipline itself. ethnographic monographs have dealt with the economies
of the people under discussion as a matter of course. The evolutionists were
fundamentally interested in levels of technology and environmental “adaptations,”
and functionalists interpreted all social systems in terms of the satisfaction
of basic human needs. Subsequently, anthropologists influenced by Marx would
see a given society’s “mode of production” as determinant, at least in the last
instance, of politics, law, and ideology. Even though none of these theoretical
paradigms dominates the field today, it is generally accepted that compelling
accounts of social and symbolic behavior must relate them to the material organization
of society. Economics is such an integral part of anthropological studies that a
separate branch of economic anthropology has been developed.
Brief history:
The interface between economics and anthropology follows a
three phase of development.
The purpose of economic anthropology in the nineteenth
century was to test the claim that a world economic order must be founded on
the principles that underpinned Western industrial society. The search was on
alternatives that might support a more just economy, wheather liberal,
socialist, anarchist or communist. Since, society was understood to have not
yet reach its final form, there was great interest in origins and evolution.
Anthropology was thus the most inclusive way of thinking about economic
possibilities. Therefore, in the first phase most anthropoligists were
interested in whether the economic behaviour of the ‘savages’ was underpinned
by the same notions of ‘raitonality’ that
were taken to motivate economic action in the West. The result was the famous
formalist-substantivist debate. Formalist-Substantivist Debate is the dispute
in Economic Anthropology between those scholars who argue that formal rules of
neoclassical economic theory derived from the study of capitalist market
societies can be used to explain the dynamics of premodern economies ("formalists")
and those who argue that goods and services in the substantive economy are
produced and distributed through specific cultural contexts
("substantivists"). Formalists contend that because all economies
involve the rational pursuit of, access to, and use of, scarce resources by
self-interested, maximizing social actors, formal economic rules can be used to
explain them (H. Schneider 1974). Substantivists, by contrast, contend that
different forms of exchange have different sets of rules and expectations
(Dalton 1961). Following Karl Polanyi the substantivists argue that there are
three major forms of exchange: reciprocity, redistribution, and market exchange
(K. Polanyi et al. 1957). By this view, the rational, maximizing strategizing
that lies at the heart of neoclassical economics and formalist economic
anthropology is characteristic only of market economies.
In this phase the debate was whether mainstream approaches
and methodologies of studying economics was adequate for studying economics of pre-industrial
– especially ‘tribal’ society or not. Formalists held that the tools of
mainstream economics were adequate to this task, while, ‘substantivists’ were
of the opinion that institutional approaches is more apt to study a substantive
economy (Le Clair and Schneider 1968). Substantivists argued that economic life
of substantive societies are embedded in other social institutions, ranging
from the household to government and religion (Hart 2008).
The formalist-substantivist debate has been replaced by more
enduring issues such as Marxist approach (Seddon 1978) and Feminists approach (Moore
1988). Eventually, with globalisation and neo-liberal opening up of markets in
post-colonial nations anthropologists started to include more aboutfill range
of human economies and not just the exotic economics. We all now live in one
world driven by capitalism, so anthropologists have studied that. There was a
marked shift back home to the Western heartlands : but in real sense of a
shrinking world, anthropologists are encouraged to develop new ways of studying
‘globalisation’ everywhere (Eriksen 2007).
Enduring issues:
Anthropologists today are dealing with the following issues
with increasing close working relationship with economics:
Informal economy:
Is an outcome of attempts to see what happens to the rural
people who migrates to the cities (Hart 1973). Anyone who visits the sprawling
cities of what once called ‘the Third World’ can see that their streets are
teeming with life, a constantly shifting crowd of hawkers, porter, taxi
drivers, beggers, pimps, pickpockjeters, hustlers - all of them getting by without the benefit o
a ‘real jon’. Ethnographic study of this phenomenon generated the principal
contribution made by anthropologists to development studies and economics.
One World Capitalism:
This results from a shift in the centre of production from
so called developed nations to countries with cheaper labour like China, India
and Brazil. This is most important feature of recent decade. In the neoliberal
homelahds, a wave of outsourcing, downziging and casualization of the labour
force undercut the political power of the unions and implied that the Western
masses now participated in the capitalism primarily as consumers rather than
producers.
Money economy and crisis:
The traditional substantivist understanding of the function of
money in economies of pre-industrial societies have gathered enough evidence to
teach the ‘modern’ money based economics what do to avert financial and
economic crisis. Anthropologists have unearthed in what ways money based
economics is seen as informal and contractual by the ‘pre-modern’ societies and
that they have developed their own mode of economic practices coupling with
money and their traditional means of subsistence economy.
Approaches:
Marxist approach
The Marxist anthropologists of
the 1960s and 1970s made much more profound theoretical attempts to wrestle
with noncapitalist economies. Althusser’s structuralist reading of Marx
identified the analytic tools that might be extracted from Marx’s study of the
rise of industrial capitalism and applied to alternative social formations.
Meillassoux is considered the first anthropologist to analyze a precapitalist society
in Marxist terms with his study of the Guro of Côte d’Ivoire (1964). Rather
than applying Marx’s unsatisfactory prefabricated constructs of “Asiatic” or
“slave”mode of production, he identified a lineage mode of production by
analyzing the direction of surplus extraction in Guro society. In this work and
in his subsequent Maidens, Meal, and Money (1981), Meillassoux pointed
to the central importance of biological reproduction as a means of production
in a situation of abundant land and relatively capital-poor technology.
Cultural ecology to political economy
With some exceptions, American anthropologists never adopted
a Marxist problematic in the way that French and some British anthropologists
did. There was, however, a turn to materialist principles of explanation in the
1960s and 1970s, as the ecological determinisms of an earlier period (Julian
Steward, Leslie White) were revisited. Orlove categorized this work as
neoevolutionist (Elman Service, Marshall Sahlins) and neofunctionalist (Marvin
Harris, Andrew Vayda, Roy Rappaport). The latter group tended to view human
societies and their environments as interactive systems, taking inspiration
from the systems theory.Marshall Sahlins described a state of primitive abundance,
calculating the resources required for hunters and gatherers to supply their
needs and observing that their societies did not induce scarcity of
want-satisfying means. Marvin Harris and Elman Service worked out different
versions of the evolution of human society and culture in terms of adaptations to
environmental constraints, the former tending to a techno-environmental
determinism. Roy Rappaport derived the ecologically adaptive functions of
various religious and ritual observances. Although materialist and evolutionary,
none of this work was historical or dialectical.
Eric Wolf emphatically introduced history when he turned to
dependency and world systems theory for a reappraisal of anthropology’s modus
operandi. Dependency theory had been elaborated by radical economists working
in Latin America and Africa who argued, against development and modernization theory,
that global integration was serving to underdevelop peripheral regions of the
globe at the expense of the capitalist “core.”Wallerstein examined the ways European
imperialist expropriations had financed the industrial revolution at the
expense of the colonies. The new attention to global interconnection took anthropology
by storm.
Exchange and value:
In The Social Life of Things, Appadurai made an
appeal for the utility of examining exchange independently of production
(although it might be argued that this is what non-Marxist anthropology has
been doing since Malinowski reported on the kula ring or since Paul Bohannan
brought back proof of Polanyi’s ideas about the social embeddedness of trade
from the Tiv). For a Marxist anthropologist, to look at exchange without considering
production is to participate in ideological mystification. For most
anthropologists, however, exchange processes offer a rich field for examining the
cultural construction of meaning and value. Much anthropological and
ethnohistorical work has addressed the historical exchange of objects across cultural
space, where the meanings of the objects transacted are a matter of contest. In
the early part of the century, Mauss drew widely on existing ethnographic
sources to describe a kind of exchange in “archaic” societies that was
essentially the opposite of the commodity fetishism of capitalist exchange. Anthropologists
have taken up Mauss’s ideas about the relationships of debt and obligation
created through gift exchange as a fundamental mechanism of social cohesion.
Apart from Gregory’s attempt to ground gifting in specific social relations of production
and reproduction, most of the theoretical impact of gifting seems to have been
registered outside of the subdiscipline of economic anthropology.
See also:
Political economy in Anthropology: https://sumananthromaterials.blogspot.in/2011/10/political-economy-in-anthropology.html
Economic Anthropology: https://sumananthromaterials.blogspot.in/2011/09/economic-anthropology.html
Branches of Social-Cultural Anthropology: https://sumananthromaterials.blogspot.in/2014/11/branches-of-social-cultural-anthropology.html
No comments:
Post a Comment